Climate change could impact the poor much more than previously thought
A new study is the first to incorporate empirical estimates of climate change impacts on economic growth in models Its widely accepted that climate change will have bigger negative impacts on poorer countries than wealthy ones. However, a new economic modeling study finds that the economic impacts on these poorer countries could be much larger than previous estimates. As a result, they suggest that we should be aiming to limit global warming to near, or perhaps even less than the international target of 2C. This conclusion is in sharp contrast to current economic models, which generally conclude that the economically optimal pathway results in a global surface warming around 33.5C . Current economic models mainly treat economic growth as an external factor. In these models, global warming and its impacts via climate change dont significantly affect the rate at which the economy grows. However, several economic studies have concluded that this is an inaccurate assumption, with a 2012 paper by Melissa Dell and colleagues taking the first stab at quantifying the effects of climate damages on economic growth. The new study by Frances Moore and Delavane Diaz of Stanford University calibrates the climate damage functions in one of these economic models ( DICE , developed by William Nordhaus at Yale) using the results from the Dell paper. They grouped the world into rich and poor countries, finding that while the economies of rich countries continue to grow well in a warmer world, the economic growth of poor countries is significantly impaired. As a result, Moore and Diaz conclude that the economically optimal pathway could be very similar to the most aggressive scenario considered by the IPCC ( called RCP2.6 ). In this scenario, human carbon emissions peak almost immediately and then decline until they reach zero around the year 2070. Moore and Diaz find that if climate change does affect GDP growth in this way, then the best path for society would limit temperatures to between 1.6 and 2.8C warming in 2100, with a best estimate of around 1.7C warming. The study estimates the impact on economic growth in poor countries if we continue on a business-as-usual carbon pollution and rapid climate change path: The average annual growth rate in poor regions is cut from 3.2% to 2.6%, which means that by 2100 per-capita GDP is 40% below reference. One challenge is that there are two factors that may contribute to the bigger impact of climate change on economic growth in poorer countries, and we dont know which effect is bigger. As poor countries are, on average, hotter than rich countries, they are exposed more frequently to damaging temperatures and therefore show higher sensitivity to temperature. Under this mechanism, the sensitivity of rich countries would increase as they warm. Alternatively, higher temperatures may be more damaging in poor countries because their economies are reliant on climate-exposed sectors such as agriculture and natural resource extraction, or because risk management options such as insurance or air conditioning are not as widely available. In this case we would expect the sensitivity of poor regions to warming to decrease as per-capita GDP increases. In other words, poorer countries may have the resources to adapt to climate change as they become wealthier in the future. On the other hand, if their economic growth is sensitive to global warming mainly because theyre located in hotter parts of the planet, then their economies will struggle in a hotter future world. The social cost of carbon is an estimate of the costs of carbon pollution to society via climate damages. Its an important number in terms of setting federal policy. In May 2013, the US government revised its estimate of the social cost of carbon from $22 per ton of carbon dioxide emitted to $37 per ton, to great consternation from the Republican Party . The new figure was based in large part on the average of the estimates from current economic models. However, Moore and Diaz conclude that when accounting for climate impacts on economic growth, the social carbon cost rises to between about $70 and $400, with a best estimate of over $200 per ton. This suggests that even the new, higher US government estimate is too low. Frances Moore told me, Our estimate of $200 per ton includes the assumption that there will be fairly rapid and effective adaptation to climate change impacts. If there is no adaptation, then the social cost of carbon is substantially larger. So its not an either / or choice between adaptation and mitigation policy. The results of this study also suggest that estimates of the social cost of carbon to date have underestimated the already large uncertainty in its value. This suggests that climate policies should focus on risk management , as Delavane Diaz explains, Rather than attempt to identify a single exact value for the social cost of carbon, mitigation policy should be designed with the goal being to manage uncertain climate risks. Theres another important take-away from this study. There have been a lot of arguments , based on current economic models, that the costs from climate damages wont be so large, and that we should instead focus on other problems. By failing to account for the impacts of climate damages on economic growth, to date these models appear to have significantly underestimated their costs. When accounting for the full impacts of climate damages, theres a strong economic case for immediate aggressive efforts to cut carbon pollution.